Ronan Lyons | Personal Website
Ronan Lyons | Personal Website

February 2012

Information a key ingredient to having a healthy property market

The imminent publication of the house price register, where from June this year all members of the public will be able to find out the transaction price of a particular property, can only be welcomed by those interested in restoring Ireland’s moribund property market to some sense of normality.

The recent economic history of Ireland’s property market is well known, not only in this country but the world over. From the 1990s until the mid-2000s, the world economy was one of many buoyant property markets. Since 2007, prices in many major markets, including large parts of Europe and the U.S., have fallen significantly. And in that story, Ireland sticks out, with the largest rise in house prices of any developed economy in the decade to 2007 – 300% if anyone needs reminding – and the largest fall in the five years since – over 50% as of late 2011.

Why Ireland sticks out

But why was Ireland’s bubble-crash cycle so vicious? While there is a long list of potential suspects, three factors that distinguish Ireland from most other countries must shoulder the lion’s share of the blame. One was opening the floodgates of Eurozone credit to an Irish banking system that had up to that point only ever been used to having to fight for every pound. A second factor was Ireland’s extraordinarily generous treatment of property as a form of wealth: Ireland was, as of 2005, the only modern economy where citizens neither paid an annual property tax nor capital gains if they sold their house at a profit. (Indeed, the situation is worse now, with the only substantial property market tax that existed in 2005, stamp duty, effectively abolished.)

The third factor – and perhaps the least excusable – was the poor quality of information available to those transacting in the property market. To see why this matters so much, we need to go back to how the property market works. The price paid for a property today reflects people’s expectations of what they think will happen property prices tomorrow, next year and over the coming generation. This makes our expectations of fundamental importance.

People’s expectations of house prices are what economists call adaptive: if they see prices having risen by 60% in the last five years, most assume that something similar will happen the next five years. And sure enough, if you look at the ESRI survey of consumer confidence from early 2007, most people thought that house prices would increase by as much between 2007 and 2012 as they had done between 2002 and 2007.

The importance of expectations

But of course we know that is not what happened. So part of ensuring that the bubble and crash we have just experienced never again happens involves not only fixing how banks themselves borrow – and how society taxes property – but also improving how people form their expectations of house prices. Think back to bubble-era Ireland. Then, we had a situation where the price of an off-plan apartment would be higher on a Monday than the previous Friday. Why? Because in the frenzy, nobody knew what anything was really selling for – and to avoid getting caught out, they effectively gazumped themselves.

The best tool to fight this type of situation is information and the house price register is the most obvious step forward. There will of course be those that think it is nothing but an annoying invasion of privacy. But they need to think of others. After all, buying a home is the largest transaction that most people will ever engage in – surely it is only reasonable that we give our young families as much information as possible before they take the plunge.

The house price register will do this. Members of the public will be able to go on to a map of Ireland, click on their area of interest and see all recent transactions, their addresses and their prices. In the early years, it seems other information – such as property type, building size or site size – won’t yet be available but given the huge amount of work being done in digitizing Land Registry records and local authority Development Plans, it’s only a matter of time before the “informational infrastructure” available to Irish people becomes even better.

Aside from perhaps the labour market, there is no more important market in any modern economy than housing. In Ireland, we (still) hold some €300bn in residential property alone. All types of real estate make up probably three quarters of our wealth, while housing makes up more of the country’s “basket of goods” than any other good or service. The links between housing and the broader economy have gone from being underappreciated by economists ten years ago to a hot topic of research now. In the Ireland of 2012, with widespread unemployment, negative equity and growing mortgage arrears, those links are all too real.

Make no mistake – the house price register will not be a panacea. But it is an important step in normalising Ireland’s property market and creating a healthier link between it and the rest of the economy.

This post originally appeared as an op-ed in the Irish Independent last week. It does not seem to be available online but its companion piece, by Michael Brennan, is available here.

Would you rather tax gardens or jobs? The Site Value Tax debate

Recently, reading the Irish Independent has been a bit of a rollercoaster for me – one day I’m practically doing the government’s job for it for free, the next I’m guilty of elder abuse. By way of context, in late January, I presented at the Dublin Economics Workshop Conference on Irish Economic Policy. Specifically, I presented on how a Site Value Tax might be introduced in this country, both on an interim basis and on a full-time basis – a podcast of the entire property market session is over on the irisheconomy.ie website.

My proposal – full report here – was relatively straightforward: use the best information we have currently (1.3 million sales and lettings ads posted on daft.ie between 2006 and 2011), and the best methods available for establishing the components of house prices (hedonic price regressions) to implement the best known form of taxation (Site Value Tax) on an interim basis, in an area where Ireland desperately needs new revenues: residential property. And when better information becomes available – in particular the Revenue Commissioners register of transactions – then that can be used for a full Site Value Tax. My map outlining relative land values in 4,500 districts across the country is reproduced below.

4,500 districts of Ireland put into one of ten land value bands, for the purposes of an interim SVT

SVT: the sales pitch

A Site Value Tax (SVT) is an annual tax that is paid on the value of the land that you own. If you own a four-bed semi-detached in suburban Dublin worth €400,000, you can think of that €400,000 as being the value of the building (say €300,000) added to the value of the land (say €100,000). Your tax bill would be something like 2% of the €100,000.

Why do I say SVT is the best known form of taxation? Ultimately, because it’s fair and efficient. It’s that rarest of taxes, popular with not only both left- and right-wings but also with environmentalists. Left-wingers like Site Value Tax because ultimately real estate is the single biggest form of wealth – and what left-winger worth their salt doesn’t like a wealth tax? Right-wingers like Site Value Tax because it does not distort economic outcomes: land can’t go anywhere, unlike pretty much every other input you can think of, so just because it’s taxed doesn’t mean that rents have to go up or that business has to move elsewhere. And environmentalists like Site Value Tax because it encourages the best use of land, which is a scarce resource. Why would you keep a site derelict if you’re getting taxed as much as the same the guy next door making that land work?

A Site Value Tax is particularly appealing when viewed in the context of local government. Think back to why any land you own is worth more than agricultural land. It’s because of a range of amenities to which your land offers access – from public services like education, health and public safety, through environmental amenities like urban green space, coastline or lakes, to more intangible services, such as access to thick labour or consumer markets. Unlike, say, the value associated with shares in a firm, no one person or group of people creates the value associated with land – society does and thus SVT is the return that society gets for creating the amenities we enjoy.

SVT: glitches and hitches

The Irish property-owner, however, may not be as impressed with such lofty talk. What about those who bought in the boom and who are now stuck in negative equity? What about those, such as elderly couples, who are land-rich but cash-poor? What about those who live on rural sites that might be ten, fifty or even a hundred times the size of those in urban homes?

A Site Value Tax fundamentalist would say that none of this matters. Those who bought during the boom are not going to un-buy because this tax is brought in and besides the SVT reflects current land values, not bubble-era values. They would argue that those who are land-rich but cash-poor should be encouraged to move on, as a country where every set of parents who refuse to downsize on retirement push their own children’s homes further out. And a country of large rural sites imposes greater costs on urban dwellers subsidising their scattered neighbours – thus a site value tax should – and would – reflect this, they would argue.

A Site Value Tax realist knows that these things matter. Hence I prepared a series of FAQs in the full report prepared for Smart Taxes and the Department of the Environment, available here. Bubble-era buyers, for example, could be given a graduated tax credit from introduction of SVT for a five-year period (similar to mortgage interest relief). After this, 2004-2008 buyers would be liable for the same amount of tax as their neighbours on similar plots.

Those with large plots of land but little income – in particular pensioners – could easily be accommodated with the use of lien on the property, where the tax bill is postponed until the property is ultimately sold. And rural dwellers will almost certainly pay less than their urban counterparts anyway, with such a large differential between urban land values and residential ones. Allowing rural landowners to decide once and for all which of their land is residential and which agricultural would also assuage fears that rural life would be irrevocably destroyed.

In truth, any lobby group can be accommodated – we just need to be clear that this is what we’re doing. We’re shifting the burden from one group on to the rest of society. We may have good reasons for doing this but we shouldn’t fall for emotive arguments that try and disguise that.

One lobby group I think we should pander to is people, as opposed to empty land. What do I mean by this? Suppose we have two adjacent 1-acre city centre site. One owner leaves theirs empty (Case A) while the other builds 100 apartments, each worth €200,000, and rents them out (Case B). In case A, the site is worth €5m and in case B the block is worth €20m, of which the site is worth €5m.

Under a full property value tax, the empty site has a liability of €25,000 while the apartment block pays €100,000. It seems very unfair, though, that the site being used productively, from society’s point of view, has to pay the burden of the tax. Under a 1% SVT, both sites would pay a tax of €50,000 – already the person leaving their site empty is being encouraged to use their site to generate a return.

Now, suppose there were a 2% site value tax but with a per-person “green space” tax credit of €250 (roughly 1% of an acre per person, at a nationwide average per-acre value of €25,000). If the 100 apartments housed 250 people, that would mean the apartment block receives tax credits of €62,500, off their bill of €100,000, while the empty site is hit with a full tax bill €100,000. This modified SVT would shift the burden of taxation on to zoned-but-undeveloped land.

SVT: making us rich?

How much could SVT raise? The tax I proposed worked off an assumption that the Goverment would like to emulate best practice in this area and generate about €2bn in residential property tax annually – this is where the €625 per household figure from the press came from. If applied to commercial property also, a full SVT which replaced commercial rates, stamp duties and the 80% windfall tax, would constitute about €1bn in new revenue streams.

The natural response of anyone to the suggestion of a new taxation averaging €625 a year is “No thanks” (or possibly worse). To argue this, though, is effectively an argument for higher income tax and higher VAT. This is because everyone agrees that Ireland needs to raise about €4.5bn in new tax revenues over the coming years (€4.65bn by 2015, according to the 2011 Medium-Term Fiscal Statement) and even if organic growth delivers, as the Department of Finance expects, €1.4bn, that’s €3.25bn needed through fresh taxation measures.

Ultimately, there are only three types of taxes: those on incomes (which hurt competitiveness), those on consumption (which are bad for equity) and those on wealth, including property. So those who argue out of hand against a property tax such as SVT are arguing for the €3.3bn in new revenue streams to come entirely from some combination of income taxes or consumption taxes, both of which hurt jobs. And with Ireland’s VAT rate the highest in the world outside the Nordic countries and Ireland’s income tax rates among the highest in the world, the scope in these areas is limited.

For me, the key point is that when a full property tax is proposed, it needs to be done as part of an array of alternatives. The Minister cannot simply say, in the context of needing to raise €2bn: “Here’s our idea for a property tax. Do you like it?” No matter how nice the tax is on paper, the answer is going to be overwhelmingly “NO!”. Any property tax needs to be proposed as one of two (or three) options: “We can either introduce this property tax, or else we will need to raise the lower rate of income tax from 20% to 25%. Both harm disposable incomes but only one harms the creation of jobs. Which one do you want?”

A bold postcript

Note that the €625 average figure above was an input of the research (we need this to raise €2bn), not an outcome. The tax could be introduced at any level. At €100 a household, it could merely replace the household charge – but that’s not going to fund too many local amenities.

Alternatively, and much more boldly, the introduction of a 10% SVT on residential and commercial property – which would raise perhaps close to €10bn – could be done in conjunction with a reduction in VAT and a reduction in income taxes. This would help close the deficit, boost Ireland’s competitiveness, improve the fairness of the tax system and encourage efficient use of land. What’s not to like?

Buyer power: Latest rent figures suggest review of rent supplement will have an impact

Where is there oversupply in the Irish rental market? And where might there be shortgages? This post reviews the figures from the latest Daft.ie Rental Report, whose commentary is given by Minister Joan Burton. The headline figures suggest stability in rents, but that hides very different trends between the major urban markets, Dublin and Cork in particular, and the smaller rental markets. A comparison of supply and demand across the country suggests that rents should be falling faster in many parts of the country – turning the focus back on to rent supplement levels. Read more